Expanding economic thinking;
Shrii Sarkar and Amartya Sen
Sohail Inayatullah
There is a general sense of exuberance that with the recent Nobel award going
to a social welfare economist the trend away from financial markets being
primary has been validated by the economics profession. It is thus heartening
that the Nobel Committee has finally discovered the People's economy.
We say finally because it has been the people's economy for thousands of
years that has nourished us, that has kept us alive. Whatever the historical
era - shudra, ksattriya, vipra or vaeshya - it is this level of the economy
that has been most crucial, and it is this economy that those in power have
been most concerned about dominating.
When capitalists are in power, they want to ensure to monetize the informal
dimensions of barter, of small markets, of localism. They want to ensure
that the far reaches of corporatization expand to the most remote village
so that there can be paying customers for their products; customers who can
pay in cash and not in-kind through bartering.
When vipras are in power, they too want to ensure that there is surplus
at the bottom level so their welfare can be taken care of. They want to ensure
that every last bit segment of the market is appropriately taxed.
Too, in ksattriyan eras, warriors take from the poor for their dreams of
conquering neighbors. Indeed, history can be understood from this dimension
- who is taking from the peoples economy, what ways have been found to extract
wealth upward. Is it through donations to priests and monks, is it calls
to globalize, is it through monetization? By analyzing in which ways the
people are removed from direct economic activities we can gauge what level
of exploitation exists.
DEFINED
But what specifically is the People's
economy? Shrii Sarkar defines it as such: "People's economy deals with the essential needs of the people
- the production, distribution, marketing ... and all related activities
of such essential needs. Most importantly, it is directly required concerned
with the guaranteed provision of minimum requirements such as food, clothing,
housing, medical treatment, education, transportation, energy and irrigation
water." (i). At essence, it is about survival. With a vibrant peoples
economy, people live, without it, as Sen has argued, famines can result.
And yet, it is this economy that the state tries to regulate. Again as Sen
has shown famines result partly due to state intervention, especially in
immoral dictatorships where there is no opposition, where people have no
way to express their frustrations, where information is kept secret. In contrast,
a people's economy is decentralized, local, and ideally based on the cooperative
economic model, wherein individuals exist in community, in relationship with
each other.
This message of localism has been
the most recent wave of economic thinking. Thinkers such as Hazel Henderson,
James Robertson and representatives of
indigenous communities have consistently argued that the opposite of capitalism
is not communism but localism - that to survive we need to (1) focus on the
environment - a concern for animals and plants, (2) focus on just distribution
- on the ratio of wealth between the richest and poorest, (3) focus on local
forms of exchange, including local money, (4) focus on the most vulnerable
- often women and children, and (5) find ways to empower these groups not
by "developing" them but by removing the barriers that vipras,
ksattriyas and vaeshyas place in front of them, that is the barriers that
intellectuals/priests; police/military and merchants/capitalists place on
them. The goal is not to help these people become rich (as defined by those
in power) but to ensure their dignity and their survival, to empower them.
While emergency help though social relief organizations is important, far
more crucial is removing the power of the landlords, of the courts, the police,
and larger corporations. Doing both of course is what states find problematic.
WHY?
Feeding the poor is admired but asking why the poor are hungry, and then
taking steps to eliminate the barriers of poverty is what threatens governments,
for it exposes that those in power are unwilling to transform the structural
basis of violence, of poverty. It is precisely this reason why Shrii Sarkar
and his social movements - Ananda Marga and Prout - have been at the receiving
end of brutality from state and national governments in India and elsewhere.
Sen wins an award because he theorises poverty, Mother Teresa wins an award
because she relieves human suffering - both are deserving winners - but Shrii
Sarkar, who theorizes poverty, relieves human suffering and initiates powerful
movements to expose and end poverty was vilified. Of course, we should not
be surprised by this. As he says himself, whenever truth has been spoken
to power, the response has been an attack on truth. This is the natural cycle
transformative movements must endure if they are to create the conditions
for a better life for future generations.
Finally, and this is crucial, and again problematic from a reductionist
modernist perspective, Shrii Sarkar has included inner, personal transformation
as part of the solution to poverty and injustice. Unless humans begin the
inner purification moral process themselves as well as the mental expansionary
process - through meditation - they, over time, will also become part of
the problem. The structures of exploitation - that is, the institutions,
the values and persons who legitimise and validate them - have too deeply
infected society. Only by enhancing one's morality and expanding the inclusiveness
of one's mind is it possible to avoid the dis-ease of an unjust system. It
is this combination that makes Shrii Sarkar both utterly unique and fundamentally
problematic to grasp. It might even have been enough, as mentioned above,
to theorise, relieve and challenge poverty but then to investigate inner
poverty, the lack of spiritual nourishment, immediately relocates poverty
not only as a food issue for the poor but as well a global moral and spiritual
issue. The solution thus becomes not just less authoritarian systems, and
a better framework for distributive justice - Sen's argumenmt - but inner
and outer systemic and epistemic transformation. It is thus grand sweep of
self and society that Shrii Sarkar brings to economic thinking, and in the
process fundamentally redefines the field.
OTHER SYSTEMS
Returning to the more specific issue of the people's economy, it is important
to note that communism as well spoke of the people's economy, indeed, the
entire philosophy was based on protecting the people, on ending wage labor
exploitation, but there were two problems. (1) Politics instead of being
landlord-laborer based became party apparatchik-laborer based. (2) Violence
was systematically used against localism so that there could be massive industrialisation.
(3) Dignity, in terms of local religions, customs and ways of knowing, was
jettisoned for progress. While in some cases this can be justified, that
is, where religion and other systems are conducive toward violence against
the other, in many cases, localism was quickly replaced with allegiance to
party, ideology and the great leader. Thus one dogma was replaced by another.
Confucianism as well has attempted
to end the people's economy but in a far more benign way. The trade off
for ending local systems has been the
paternal state where father knows best. While this has had its merits - safety,
security, survival, education, a concern for the family and future generations,
transparent politics - the loss has been cultural pluralism, of the right
to dissent. While certainly for a "well knit social order" - to
use Shrii Sarkar's language - dissent should only come with responsibility,
it appears that in Confucian societies the spirit of difference, the sweetness
of culture, has been lost.
Globalism, while absolutely brilliant at the continuous movement of money,
its rolling, has been less concerned about where the money is going, the
ethical in and outputs. It has been excellent at economic growth but less
with distribution. Moreover, the rolling of money has been based not on productive
investment but on short-term speculation, thus leading to a delinking of
the financial economy with the real economy of goods and services.
It is this concern for inappropriate economic practices that Sarkar's other
branch of economics, the psycho-economy, attends. to.
PSYCHO-ECONOMY
Psycho-economy has two branches,
the first of which, will never deliver a nobel in our modern world, but
the second in the coming generations should
be fundamental. The first branch consists of exposing and eradicating "unjust
economic practices, behaviors and structures." (ii) This is generally
well represented in the Marxist literature, and more or less, consistent
with the intentions of radical political-economy. Current thinkers such as
Immanuel Wallerstein and Johan Galtung have both excelled in this approach.
The second branch is concerned with a post-scarcity society, that is, with
mundane economic problems solved, how to deal with pressing issues such as
the relationship between technology and work or the office environment. These
post-industrial issues include as well: how employees feel about their lives,
about their job, and about what is important to them.
Psycho-economy is not an attempt
to create a theory of information, since Shrii Sarkar is not a reductionist
but to ask what are the values behind
an economy, what are our aspirations? It acknowledges that life is not about
economics and economistic (reducing life to materialistic principles) thinking.
As Shrii Sarkar writes: "the psycho-economy is to develop and enhance
the psychic pabula of the individual and collective minds." (iii). What
does this mean? At heart this is about inclusion, about reframing our identity
not as consumers (I shop therefore I am) or as competitors (I have to increase
my wealth by eliminating other firms) but as spiritual human beings. This
means seeing the exchange of good, services and ideas as a process wherein
others are not harmed, stolen from or maligned but creating an economic process
that allows each participant to prosper. At heart, this is about spiritual
cooperative economics, about including others in how we do business, how
we produce, how we consume, how we live. It is understanding our desires
and their relationship to the physical world. Capitalist economics, however,
ignores social costs such as the drudgery of much work or the social problems
caused by unemployment. Capitalist economics does not ask the crucial question:
is what is being produced that which should be produced for the health and
happiness of all?
Conventional economics thus defines values, impact on the environment, impact
on future generations, as external to the economic process. Indeed, critics
of globalization have called for full pricing, where externals are internalized
by economic actions. The goal thus is to increase access to information for
buyers and sellers and to determine the impact of specific economic activity
on society. While this important, it does not nearly go far enough for Sarkar.
INFORMATION ECONOMICS AND OTHER PARTS OF THE ECONOMY
Information economic theory has made the mistake of further dividing reality
into tiny bits with the goal of quantifying each further subdivision, while
Sarkar argues that the opposite is needed, an expansion of what we allow
in our minds, or how we construct our minds. With Sarkar, information theory
thus moves to communication theory with reality being a co-evolutionary process
between self, others, the transcendental and the natural world. This synthetic
approach will not win nobel or other awards since it does not give any specific
additive knowledge (what science excels at), instead it creates a new framework
in which to understand current knowledge - that is, it is transformative
knowledge.
But Sarkar's redefinition of economics
does not avoid current commercial issues. Indeed, he also writes on the
Commercial Economy. This branch is
generally similar to our present understanding of economics, which is concerned
with issues of how to develop scientific productive and efficient processes
that "which will not incur loss," (iv) and ensure that "output
will exceed input." (v) While an idealistic, Sarkar never ignored the
reality of the physical world. Indeed, he asserted that we are not properly
using our current resources, either misusing them or mal-appropriating them.
The majority of problems in the world have come about because the Commercial
Economy has been seen as the totality of economics instead of just as one
dimension of economics. While Sen brings in values to economics, he still
does this largely in the context of the commercial economy. It is left to
others to point out that the general tools of economic theory cannot deal
with the household, village or indigenous economy.
Finally, Sarkar adds the General Economy to his model. This last part is
his ideal vision of the economy. In this case, a three-tiered economic structure
(state run, cooperatives and individual/family run). Thus, while earlier
parts of the economy focused on the minimum requirements of life (that is,
the needs of the South); on the structural problems of exploitation (the
global problematique); on a postscarcity inclusive economy (the concerns
of a post-industrial economy); on issues of production and the international
monetary system (the world-economy), the last section of his theory of economics,
focuses on what an ideal economic structure should look like.
These categories he gives us - the four parts of the economy - are not only
descriptions of the economy, but as well analytic tools, that is, they serve
to describe and reveal the world in front of us.
For economic students, much of this is not economics, as economics as currently
defined is only concerned with production, and not with the values behind
the system. Issues of inflation and depression, while the concern of conventional
economics are not Sarkar's direct concern except in so far as they lead to
system transformation - the end of capitalism - or they increase human suffering.
Sarkar's Proutist Economics is then not about debating economic trends or
pinpointing depressions but rather about using the analytic tools Shrii Sarkar
has given us to better understand the world, to change the world, to relieve
human suffering, to transform self, to create a moral economy; and ultimately
to create a spiritual cooperative society.
Will Shrii Sarkar ever win a nobel prize? Most likely never, and, of course,
this was never his aim. His prize will be the creation of a new planetary
society, a prize no committee can ever give, only the hard work of women
and working collectively, and the grace of Parama Purusa can afford that.
Notes:
i. P.R.Sarkar, "The Parts of the Economy," in
P.R.Sarkar, Prout in a Nutshell. Translated by Acarya Vijayananda Avadhuta
and Jayanta Kumar.
Calcutta, Ananda Marga Publications, 1987 (First edition), 16.
ii. ibid., 19.
iii. ibid.
iv. ibid., 20.
v. ibid.,
References:
Alan Fricker, guest editor, "Beyond Capitalism," special
issue of New Renaissance, Spring, 1999.
Hazel Henderson, Building a Win-Win World: Life Beyond Global Economic Warfare.
San Francisco, Berret-Koehler Publishers, 1996.
Sohail Inayatullah, Prabhat Rainjan Sarkar - On Economics. Minneapolis,
Minnesota, Renaissance Universal Institute Publication Series No. 5, 1988.
Sohail Inayatullah and Paul Wildman, Futures Studies - Methods, Emerging
Issues and Civilisational Visions. Brisbane, Prosperity Press, 1998.
James Robertson, Beyond the Dependency Culture: People, Power and Responsibility.
Twickenham, Adamantine Press, 1998.
P.R.Sarkar, Prout in a Nutshell. Calcutta, Ananda Marga Publications, 1987
(First edition).
P.R. Sarkar, Proutist Economics: Discourses on Economic Liberation. Calcutta,
Ananda Marga Publications, 1992.
Amartya Sen, Poverty and Famines. Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1981.
Amartya Sen, "Information," www.nobel.se/announcment-98/economics98.html
Amartya Sen, "Development Economist," www.economictimes.com/151098/15opin01.htm
Acarya Shambhushivananda Avadhuta, Prout - Neo-Humanistic Economics. Weisenauer
Weg, Germany, Dharma Verlag, 1989.
Rameshwar Dayal Singh, "Poverty Alleviation is Possible," Prout
(December 1-15, 1998), 38-39.
Ted Trainer, "Our Economic
System: Why it must be scrapped." Research
paper, Faculty of Arts, University of New South Wales.